当前位置: 首页 > 期刊 > 《英国医生杂志》 > 2005年第17期 > 正文
编号:11385529
Orphan drugs and the NHS: should we value rarity?
http://www.100md.com 《英国医生杂志》
     1 White Rose Initiative in Health Technology Assessment, Health Economics and Decision Science, School of Health and Related Research, University of Sheffield, Sheffield S1 4DA, 2 White Rose Initiative in Health Technology Assessment, Centre for Health Economics, University of York, York YO1 5DD

    Correspondence to: C McCabe c.mccabe@sheffield.ac.uk

    The growing number and costs of drugs for rare diseases are straining healthcare budgets. Decisions on funding these treatments need to be made on a sound basis

    Cost effectiveness plays an important part in current decisions about the funding of health technologies. Drugs for rare disease (orphan drugs) are often expensive to produce and, by definition, will benefit only small numbers of patients. Several countries have put measures in place to safeguard research and development of orphan drugs, but few get close to meeting the cost effectiveness criteria for funding by healthcare providers. We examine the justifications for special status for rare diseases and ask whether the cost effectiveness of drugs for rare or very rare diseases should be treated differently from that of other drugs and interventions.

    Current practice

    The citizen's council of the National Institute for Health and Clinical Excellence (NICE) was recently asked to consider whether the NHS should be prepared to pay premium prices for drugs to treat patients with very rare diseases.1 It recommended that the NHS should consider paying premium prices based on three criteria: the severity of the disease, evidence of health gain, and whether the disease is life threatening.1 The decision by the Department of Health to ring fence funding for enzyme replacement therapy for lysosomal disorders, with expected annual costs above £100 000 ($180 000, 150 000) per patient for life, suggests that central government also currently believes that premium prices should be paid.2

    NICE has conducted a feasibility study to explore whether its current processes and methods of technology appraisal can be applied to the appraisal of ultra-orphan drugs (those for diseases with a prevalence of 0.18/10 000 or less).3 It has not yet stated whether it will recommend that treatments for very rare diseases should have special status during appraisal.

    To date, the institute has evaluated only one ultra-orphan drug, imatinib for gastrointestinal stromal tumours. The estimated cost per quality adjusted life year was £30 000, and its use was approved.4 Other ultra-orphan drugs may also not require special status to be considered cost effective (for example, anegralide for essential thrombocytopenia). However, these are likely to be the exception rather than the rule (table 1). The four biotech therapies licensed for the treatment of ultra-orphan diseases in the UK cost over £58 000 per person a year. The four ultra-orphan products in clinical development are also biotech products and likely to have similar price tags. These prices make it impossible for these treatments to meet conventional criteria for cost effectiveness.5

    Table 1 Examples of ultra-orphan drugs

    Orphan status

    Several jurisdictions have established regulations for orphan drugs. The United States was the first to do so, through the 1983 US Orphan Drugs Act.6 The European Union did not establish orphan drugs status until 2000. The precise prevalence threshold varies widely, with the United States having the most generous and Australia the least. (table 2).

    Table 2 Definitions of orphan diseases

    Special status for drugs for rare diseases such as neurofibromatosis may be unsustainable

    Credit: PENNY TWEEDIE/SPL

    The justifications for providing special status to orphan drugs are ambiguous and differ between jurisdictions. The US Orphan Drugs Act states: "Some promising drugs will not be developed and it is in the public interest to provide such changes and incentives for the development of orphan drugs."6 This suggests that the justification for special status is based on the cost of production and the value of innovation. The European Union legislation provides a subtly different but equally ambiguous rationale: "Patients suffering from rare conditions should be entitled to the same quality of treatment as other patients."7 In this case the rationale seems to be equity.

    A range of special measures are in place to support research and development of orphan drugs. These generally include public funding for basic science, tax incentives, extended patent protection, and market exclusivity.6 7 The issue faced by bodies such as NICE is whether a similar special status should be enshrined in decisions about allocating resources.

    Estimating cost effectiveness

    The evidence base for orphan drugs is suggested to be too sparse to allow estimates of cost effectiveness.3 However, estimates for all drugs and interventions synthesise evidence from a variety of sources, including randomised controlled trials, observational studies, and expert judgment. The resulting decision on funding must reflect the amount and quality of the evidence so that the decision is made in knowledge of the uncertainty around the estimate of cost effectiveness. Thus, even when the central estimate of the cost effectiveness is below the threshold for funding, if there is a large amount of uncertainty, the decision maker may still choose not to fund and await more evidence to reduce the uncertainty. The methods currently used by NICE are well suited to this.5 The institute has already appraised drugs for 15 rare diseases using the same methods and decision criteria as for other appraisals (see bmj.com).5

    The level of evidence required to support a decision to adopt a technology should depend on the consequences of the uncertainty—that is, if an uncertain decision proves to be wrong, how much will society lose in terms of resources and health outcomes forgone? The expected cost of uncertainty is largely determined by the number of patients affected. Therefore the existing framework of evaluation and appraisal will accept a lower level of evidence for orphan drugs because the cost of uncertainty will be lower. Existing methods not only cope with the lower levels of evidence available for orphan drugs, they support the use of lower evidential standards for orphan drugs.8

    Cost of production and value of innovation

    The justification for special status for orphan drugs is often couched in terms of the costs of developing a drug for a rare disease relative to the small market and consequently the high costs of treatment for each patient.6 7 9 The real costs faced by the pharmaceutical industry are open to argument, but the fundamental question is whether society should subsidise the private sector to invest in the development of technologies when the cost to society exceeds the value it places on the health gain produced. If the answer is no, then the costs of production cannot justify any special treatment.

    However, this analysis requires the private sector to fully anticipate all the future benefits and returns from developing treatments for rare diseases. The private sector may not fully account for these in its investment decisions if it discounts the future benefits more highly than society (because of taxation and risk), or if it fears that the longer term benefits and returns may be recouped by others. In these situations the public sector should and does intervene through directly funding research, tax incentives, and patent law to protect intellectual property rights.6 7 Existing measures may be inadequate, but even if that is true, poor incentives are not restricted to rare diseases. Any reasons for further intervention would apply to all investments in research and development. Therefore, the arguments based on the value of innovation or the cost of production cannot provide justification for special status.

    Valuation of benefits

    The argument must therefore rest on the way the immediate benefits from the treatment of rare diseases are measured and valued. The value placed on an intervention depends on the objective of the healthcare system. The often cited objective of maximising health gains is consistent with the view that clinical need can be regarded as the capacity to benefit from an intervention and that every individual's heath gain is valued equally. This view of need, and the implicit view of equity, is embedded in cost effectiveness analysis.5 But it is not consistent with the European Union's legislation stating that all patients should have equal access to the same quality of care.7 If the objective is to maximise health outcomes, the cost effectiveness of drugs for rare diseases should be treated in the same way as that of other technologies.

    A range of alternative objectives and equity principles are possible. These include equality of health outcomes, equality of resource use, or allocation of resources in proportion to the severity of the individual's ill health. However, adopting a different objective, or view of need and equity will have profound implications for allocation of resources throughout the healthcare system, not just for the treatment of rare diseases. Moreover, these competing concepts of equity are not specific to rare diseases and cannot justify their special treatment. Indeed, rare diseases may not be particularly advantaged or disadvantaged by alternative objectives and principles of equity.

    Measurement and valuation of health gain

    Measuring improvements in health outcome, in a manner which adequately captures all the effects valued by the patient, is challenging. Quality adjusted life years may not capture all that is valued in some circumstances. For example, it has been argued that treatment should be valued independently of any improvements in health when no other active treatment is available,10 when an intervention may arrest a disease process or preserve life for a time, or when prognosis is particularly poor.9 11-14 Another argument is that the valuation of health outcome should reflect the fact that known lives tend to be valued more highly than unknown statistical lives.15 This may be particularly relevant to diseases with a strong genetic component, when people who will develop the disease can be identified. Many rare diseases reflect some of these issues, but they are also relevant to more common diseases and so cannot justify special status. The appropriate response to these issues is to conduct the methodological and empirical work required to improve our measurement and valuation of outcome across diseases, whether rare or common.

    Summary points

    The appraisal framework already supports the use of lower evidential standards for orphan drugs

    The costs of production and the value of innovation cannot justify special treatment for orphan drugs

    Arguments about the measurement and valuation of health outcomes apply equally to orphan drugs and drugs for more common conditions

    Valuing health outcome more highly for rare conditions is incompatible with other equity principles and theories of justice

    The cost effectiveness of orphan drugs should be treated in the same way as for other technologies

    Equity and rarity

    The justification for special status for rare diseases must rest on the question: should we value the health gain to two individuals differently because one individual has a common disorder and the other has a rare disorder?

    Consider two groups of people who have similar diseases (J and K). J is a rare disease (1 per 10 000) and K a more common disease (1 per 1000). Imagine these people have the same personal characteristics, the same prognosis without treatment, and the same capacity to benefit from the treatments. Is it acceptable that people with J do not get treatment simply because they have a rare disease? Most would say not. However, now imagine that the cost of the orphan drug for J is higher than the treatment for K. Suppose the cost of treating one case of J is £1000, the cost of treating one case of K is £100, and the budget is £1000. Then the real choice posed by orphan status is between treating 1 person with J or 10 people with K. To argue that the patient with J should get treatment implies that that health gain of people with J should be valued 10 times higher than that of people with K. The idea that decisions should be made based on valuing health outcome more highly for no other reason than rarity of the condition seems unsustainable and incompatible with other equity principles and theories of justice. Why should a person's health be valued less simply because the condition is not rare?

    Sustainability

    There seem to be no sustainable reasons why the cost effectiveness of drugs for rare diseases should be judged differently from that of other healthcare technologies. While orphan drugs were rare, healthcare systems were able to deal with them in an ad hoc manner. But there are now over 6000 orphan diseases with over 200 treatments approved by the US Food and Drugs Administration and 64 trials currently sponsored by the US Office of Orphan Products Development.16 Genomics is expected to disaggregate currently prevalent diseases into many genetically defined distinct conditions. Orphan status is thus likely to become increasingly common.

    Orphan status is maintained for drugs with multiple indications (M Hafner, Royal College of Physicians conference on managing rare diseases, London, 5 October 2004). This enables companies to take a strategic approach to the development process in order to extract the maximum amount of public financing and minimise the financial risk. Given the commercial imperative to maximise revenue and minimise costs, it is reasonable to expect further growth in the number of rare diseases and orphan drugs. The pharmaceutical industry already seems to have identified the strategic opportunity that the licensing legislation for orphan drugs represents.17 Any special status granted to orphan drugs in decisions about allocating resources is also likely to be fully exploited.

    Special status for orphan drugs in resource allocation will avoid difficult and unpopular decisions, but it may impose substantial and increasing costs on the healthcare system. The costs will be borne by other, unknown patients, with more common diseases who will be unable to access effective and cost effective treatment as a result.

    A figure showing orphan drugs appraised by NICE is on bmj.com

    The arguments advanced in this paper benefited greatly from discussions with Ron Akehurst, Pippa Anderson, John Brazier, Anthony O'Hagan, and Mark Sculpher. David Barnett kindly gave permission for the use of the figure on bmj.com.

    Contributors and sources: The arguments advanced in this paper developed from discussions following attendance at a workshop on orphan drugs at the National Institute for Clinical Excellence in February 2004 and subsequent involvement in a seminar at the Royal College of Physicians in October 2004. CM has since been involved in a feasibility study of applying the NICE reference case methods to an ultra orphan drug, undertaken by NICE. CM, KC, and AT were jointly responsible for the conception and development of the ideas presented in this paper. They jointly drafted and reviewed the paper. CM, KC, and AT have all approved the final version of the paper. CM acts as guarantor for the paper.

    Competing interests: None declared.

    References

    National Institute for Clinical Excellence. NHS should consider paying premium prices for drugs to treat patients with very rare diseases says NICE Citizen's Council. Press release 26 Jan. www.nice.org.uk/pdf/2005_002_CitizensCouncilreport.pdf (accessed 21 Feb 2005).

    Department of Health. National designation and funding of treatment for patients with lysosomal storage disorders. www.dh.gov.uk/assetRoot/04/09/22/10/04092210.pdf (accessed 22 Feb 2005).

    Rawlins M. Managing rare diseases. London: Royal College of Physicians, 2004.

    National Institute for Clinical Excellence. Final appraisal determination: imatinib for the treatment of unresectable and/or metastatic gastro-intestinal stromal tumours. London: NICE, 2004 www.nice.org.uk/page.aspx?o=216331 (accessed 18 Aug 2005).

    National Institute for Clinical Excellence. Guide to the methods of health technology appraisal. London: NICE, 2003.

    Food and Drug Administration. Orphan drug act (as amended). www.fda.gov/orphan/oda.htm (accessed 15 November 2004).

    Regulation (EC) No 141/2000 of the European Parliament and of the Council of December 16, 1999 on orphan medicinal products. Official Journal of the European Communities 2000;43(L18): 1-5.

    Claxton K, Sculpher M, Drummond M. A rational framework for decision making by the National Institute for Clinical Excellence. Lancet 2002;360: 711-5.

    Bosenquet N. Domenighetti G, Beresniak A, Auray JP, Crivelli L, Richard L, et al. Equity, access and economic evaluation in rare diseases: the impact of orphan drug legislation on health policy and patient care. Pharm Dev Reg 2003;1: 151-7.

    Nord E. Cost-value analysis in health care: making sense out of QALYs. Cambridge University Press, 1999.

    Harris J. Qualifying the value of life. J Med Ethics 1987;13: 117-23.

    Olsen JA. Theories of justice and their implications for priority setting in health care. J Health Econ 1997;16: 625-40.

    Hadorn DC. Setting health-care priorities in Oregon—cost-effectiveness meets the rule of rescue. JAMA 1991265 : 2218-25.

    McKie J, Richardson J. The rule of rescue. Soc Sci Med 2003;56: 2407-19.

    Jenni KE, Loewenstein G. Explaining the `identifiable victim effect'. J Risk Uncertainty 1997;14: 235-57.

    US Food and Drugs Administration. Grants awarded by the OOPD grant program. www.fda.gov/orphan/grants/awarded.htm (accessed 22 Feb 2005).

    De Varax A, Lettelier M, Bortlein M. Study on orphan drugs. Phase II: consideration on the application of article 8.2 of EU regulation 141/2000 concerning orphan drugs. Paris: Alcimed, 2004.(Christopher McCabe, professor of health )